2020年11月25日 星期三

Herbert Simon 的 《管理行為》和《人工科學》;自學AI的技術 (雲象科技五歲了! 2020); An Optimal Transportation (OT) View of Generative Adversarial Networks (GANs)

 

Herbert Simon 的 《管理行為》和《人工科學》;自學AI的技術 (雲象科技五歲了! 2020); An Optimal Transportation (OT) View of Generative Adversarial Networks (GANs)

今早看北京清華大學有"數據學院" (2019的,應更早)。

為什麼深度學習這麼強勁有力?How does DL work?
數據模式、流形分佈
深度學習的黑箱
嘗試從經典數學理論來加以理解……
更多


英國LSE課程廣告 Machine Learning: Practical Applications (Learn to apply machine learning models to data sets in R to inform business decisions.)



在剛得到天使投資時,雲象內部還沒有任何AI的技術。我在成立公司之前,就已經注意到深度神經網路在影像辨識上的驚人效能,美國已經開始有一些AI新創公司成立。我認為AI輔助診斷的應用會是推動病理科數位轉型最重要的力量,因此我積極的想要尋找合作夥伴一起研發數位病理AI的應用。在2017年初時,公司總共只有四個人。因為公司的規模實在太小,遍尋不著合作的夥伴。我心中篤定AI是公司發展的重要關鍵,於是做了公司發展歷史上最重要的決定,自學AI的技術。我花了半年的時間,從機器學習概論開始,接著學習深度神經網路,紮實地完成了幾個線上課程,接著開始嘗試找醫院進行AI的合作。   ~雲象科技五歲了! 2020      


月初碰到Peter,我跟他說AI 入門 (1995時世界先進的AI 摘要報告在Herbert Simon 的 《管理行為》和《人工科學》(我的錯,沒將我的譯本出版)。

2020年10月19日 星期一

Deaton, Angus (2013). The Great Escape: Health, Wealth, and the Origins of Inequality財富大逃亡:健康、財富與不平等的起源





Nobel Prize


"We forget that ageing is a really good thing and a great achievement. Ageing is a great mark of success!"
Happy 75th birthday to economist Angus Deaton, who was awarded the 2015 Prize in Economic Sciences "for his analysis of consumption, poverty, and welfare."





  • Deaton, Angus (2013). The Great Escape: Health, Wealth, and the Origins of Inequality. Princeton: Princeton University Press. ISBN 9780691153544.
財富大逃亡:健康、財富與不平等的起源
作 者Angus Deaton
譯 者李隆生, 張逸安
出版者聯經
出版日期2015年11月05日
ISBN9789570846409
登錄號C275339
索書號551.81 883

2015 年諾貝爾經濟學獎得主 代表著作
迪頓 (Angus Deaton) 關心全球窮人,要他們過好日子
他分析為何人類獲得有史以來最好的生活水準
深入探討因此而產生的貧富差距及不平等現象
諾貝爾頒獎委員會說:迪頓把應用經濟學發揮得淋漓盡致!


比爾蓋茲、普林斯頓大學校長艾斯格魯柏、賓州大學普列斯頓教授、耶魯大學波吉教授、《紐約時報》、《金融郵報》、《商業世界》、《金融時報》、《彭博資訊新聞》、《經濟與政治周刊》、《商業經濟學》、《周日泰晤士報》、《富比士雜誌》等媒體大力推薦

如果你想了解為何人類的整體福祉隨著時間而進步快速,一定要讀本書。──比爾 . 蓋茲 (Bill Gates)

現今人們變得更富裕、更健康、更長壽
然而當大量人口脫離貧窮後
人與人、國與國之間卻形成極大的不平等!

2015 年諾貝爾經濟學獎得主、世界發展經濟與貧窮研究學家──迪頓
探討各國增進健康、財富的舊有和現行模式
提出援助落後國家展開大脫逃的具體作法

迪頓在《財富大逃亡:健康、財富與不平等的起源》一書中闡述某些影響廣大的創新與不易克服的障礙,例如,人類一方面擁有了疫苗、抗生素、防蟲措施和潔淨水源,一方面必須對抗大饑荒、愛滋病和文明疾病。除了檢視美國歷經長期繁榮之後成長步調趨緩、貧富差距漸增的情況,也提到印度與中國的經濟成長如何改善十多億人口的生活。有鑑於國際援助成效不彰,甚至有害無益,迪頓在書末倡議採取替代措施,包括對製藥公司提供新誘因、取消貿易限制等,讓開發中國家也能展開大脫逃。

迪頓撰寫本書的主旨在討論全球的健康與財富,不僅聚焦於現代,也回顧人類發展的歷程。

首先,探討人類的健康發展史、數十萬年前的狩獵與採集生活為何影響現代人的健康,以及人類從十八世紀開始努力降低死亡率如何奠定現代的健康進步模式。十九世紀末,細菌致病論的發展與採納,為另一波爆炸性的進步奠定基礎,同時也打開另一道鴻溝,使得富國與窮國人民的存活率出現極大差距。

二次大戰結束後,全球加快腳步研究醫療方法,以便拉近自十八世紀開始形成的健康鴻溝。其間獲得許多重大成就,例如運用抗生素、防蟲措施、疫苗注射和乾淨水源,讓數百萬孩童免於死亡。雖然窮國與富國平均壽命差距縮小,但還不夠接近,且全球曾遭遇某些可怕的障礙,例如 1958 至 1961 年間人為因素造成的中國大饑荒,以及若干非洲國家近年流行的愛滋病,徹底摧毀了人類對抗死神的三十年進步成果。目前還有許多國家缺乏適當的常設醫護系統、大量孩童因生在「錯」的國家而難逃一死、某些地區還有孩童嚴重營養不良,以印度最出名。

富國和窮國的死亡率差距未能加速拉近的理由之一是,雖然富國的死亡率持續下降,但對成人比較有利,孩童受惠較少。也談到富國死亡率降低的趨勢、男女平均壽命不斷趨近的原因、吸菸扮演的要角,以及心臟病治癒率大於癌症治癒率的因素。

其次,討論物質生活水準。
美國的經濟狀況既特殊且極端 ( 例如所得不均的程度 ) ,但其他富裕國家也不遑多讓。二次大戰後,經濟成長為美國帶來新的榮景,使得貧窮人口 ( 尤其是非洲裔和年長者 ) 顯著減少。 1970 年代以前,美國曾是全球重要經濟楷模,此後成長持續減慢,所得差距因富人激增而持續加大。這種不平等有其光明面,例如教育、創新和創意獲得的報償高於往昔;但也顯示出黑暗面,由於美國是金權國家,導致國民的幸福受到政治和經濟的威脅。

全球貧窮人口自 1980 年開始減少,堪稱人類史上規模最大、速度最快的一次脫逃行動,主因在於人口最多的中國和印度經濟成長表現非凡,改變了十幾億人口的生活。目前全球的生活水準雖然遠勝過 1960 年代悲觀者預測的情況,但仍有約十億人口三餐不濟;許多人已經逃脫,也有不少人被遺棄。

再次,提出大家應該和不該採取的行動。我們幸運地生在「對」的國家,因此應該善盡道德義務,協助全球減少貧窮和疾病;已經掙脫貧窮和疾病的人,必須幫助依然受困者。很多人認為我們應該以提供外援的方式,以及透過多國政府 ( 大都設有官方援助機構 ) 、世界銀行和世界衛生組織等國際組織,或是在各國國內或國際上營運的非政府救援組織,來履行這些道德義務。但是,如果這類援助會破壞某些國家的成長機會 ( 這正是我的看法 ) ,我們就沒有理由抱著「應該做些什麼」的觀念繼續提供救濟,而應該停止援助。過去五十年,援助對於經濟成長和減少貧窮到底功過如何?值得質疑。

最後,迪頓提出一個問題:我們是否渴望展開大脫逃行動,為現今世界創造幸福與快樂。《財富大逃亡》剖析健康與生活水準的提升如何改變我們的生活,是討論所有國家幸福議題的重要指南。

各界盛讚

沒有人比迪頓更擅長解釋現代人為何較祖先長壽、健康和富裕,他用故事說明這不僅是人類努力邁向進步的結果,也是所得分配不平等、不均衡、不完整所致,而政治在各階段都扮演決定性的角色。本書是任何對國家財富、健康議題有興趣的人必讀的著作。──《國家為什麼會失敗》作者 艾塞莫魯 (Daron Acemoglu)

本書談論兩個最重要的歷史故事:一是人類如何獲得健康財富,二是有些人比其他人健康富裕。世界首屈一指的發展經濟學家迪頓,帶領我們踏上一段特殊旅程,從幾乎每個人都身陷貧窮和疾病的年代,走向大多數人成功掙脫這些魔掌的時代。他告訴我們,目前仍處在赤貧狀態的十億人口如何才能加入這場大逃亡。想了解 21 世紀前景的人都該讀本書。──《西方憑什麼》作者 莫里斯 (Ian Morris)

饒富趣味、筆帶同情、振奮人心的故事。──《最底層的十億人》作者 柯立爾 (Paul Collier)

這是一本內容翔實、主題嚴肅、適時出版的好書,討論愈來愈多人所得提高、壽命延長之後所衍生的問題,以及被前人幾乎視為幻想的進步成就。作者以平鋪直敘的文字風格,提出挑戰傳統觀點的有力見解。──《富人與窮人》作者 米蘭諾維科 (Branko Milanovic)

一本精采權威著作。──《白種人的負擔》作者伊斯特利 (William Easterly)

本書值得所有人一讀,特別是研究經濟發展的學生。──《經濟與政治周刊》洛伊 (Tirthankar Roy)

如果你想增加你對不平等的了解,試圖為辯論增添理智而非熱度,本書是很好的入門。──《商業經濟學》巴內特( W. Steven Barnett )

這是一本關於健康、財富與不平等的迷人著作。──《商業世界》德布洛伊 (Bibek Debroy)

一本啟發靈感的歷史,講述人類的長壽與繁榮如何在現代衝到驚人的高度……迪頓的著作以動人的敘述手法,綜觀經濟進步與醫學的里程碑,從工業革命開始,到二次大戰後速度加快,造成對壽命的預期增加。──《紐約時報》安德魯斯 (Fred Andrews)

迪頓一針見血說出:外援「多半只是滿足我們想要幫助他人的需求」,他指認出「外援幻象」(相信窮國的貧困可以經由富人給錢的方式來解決)的議題。──《金融郵報》佛斯特 (Peter Foster)

迪頓的著作清楚易懂,讚揚經濟成長帶來的財富,同時又明智地解釋為何有些人總是「被遺棄」。他明確區分兩種不平等,一是由知識的進步所產生,一是有缺失的政治體系。──《金融時報》麥克德蒙特 (John McDermott)

迪頓綜觀人類福祉的進步,充滿睿智,引發思考,可讀性極高。不論是一般或專業讀者,都能獲益良多。──《經濟紀錄》波拉德 (Jeff Borland)

本書罕見地結合高明的技巧、道德的迫切性、經驗的智慧、吸引人的易讀風格,會強化你對現代經濟成長奇蹟的了解,你也會更加相信,成長的利益可以且應該由更多人來分享。──《彭博資訊新聞》克魯克 (Clive Crook)

迪頓稱得上是現今全球頭腦最清楚的經濟發展學者。── EconomicPrincipals.com 華爾許 (David Warsh)

本書以雄辯熱切的口吻,描述疾病與健康對全球的人類及經濟有何意義。迪頓的健康與財富史敘述動人。本書提出廣泛的議題,包括為何有些國家失敗、其他國家卻成功,如何縮小兩者之間的距離等。── EH.Net  帕爾曼 (John Parman)

迪頓在書中處理全球健康與福祉的改善、國家內部與國際間不平等的程度令人擔心、透過外援治療貧窮所面臨的挑戰等重大議題。他的論述有力,引人深思,分析翔實、人本的視野、文筆流暢及挑戰傳統智慧的勇氣。不論你是否同意其結論,本書將迫使你重新思考全球最迫切的問題。── 普林斯頓大學校長 艾斯格魯柏 (Christopher Eisgruber)

迪頓對全球在健康方面進步的敘述擁有權威地位。特別具說服力的是,就健康改善的來源方面,他區分出經濟進步與科技成長。這本書講述的故事,應該會影響我們對人類發展、科學與政府的科學導向計畫等方面的想法。本書運用證據很具說服力。── 賓州大學人口學和社會學教授 普列斯頓 (Samuel Preston)

這本精彩的書討論的是,在過去兩百五十年期間,許多的人如何達成前所未見的富裕水準(過去只限少數人享用),這項成就又如何造成同樣空前的不平等。本書的焦點與視野獨特,知識特殊,前後一致,論述細心,非常具有啟發性。── 耶魯大學講座教授和全球研究中心主任 波吉 (Thomas Pogge)

2020年10月12日 星期一

Why history shows 'court packing' isn't extreme

 Expansion of the court rests in the hands of Congress, a right it has exercised several times in the nation's history, writes historian Nicole Hemmer. Rather than being "illicit" or "tyranny," as conservative critics have charged, it is an ordinary power of Congress granted by the Constitution. (via

CNN Opinion

)

Opinion: Why history shows 'court packing' isn't extreme
CNN.COM
Opinion: Why history shows 'court packing' isn't extreme
via CNN Opinion

Paul R. Milgrom and Robert B. Wilson


Paul Milgrom - Wikipedia
en.wikipedia.org › wiki › Paul_Milgr...



Paul Robert Milgrom (born April 20, 1948) is an American economist. He is the Shirley and Leonard Ely Professor of Humanities and Sciences ... Milgrom and his thesis advisor Robert B. Wilson designed the auction protocol the FCC uses to determine which phone company gets what cellular frequencies. Milgrom also led ...
Doctoral advisor: Robert B. Wilson
Fields: Economist
Doctoral students: Susan Athey; ‎Joshua Gans‎; ...‎
Nationality: American




BREAKING NEWS

The Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences has decided to award the 2020 Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel to Paul R. Milgrom and Robert B. Wilson “for improvements to auction theory and inventions of new auction formats.”
This year’s Laureates, Paul Milgrom and Robert Wilson, have studied how auctions work. They have also used their insights to design new auction formats for goods and services that are difficult to sell in a traditional way, such as radio frequencies. Their discoveries have benefitted sellers, buyers and taxpayers around the world.
People have always sold things to the highest bidder, or bought them from whoever makes the cheapest offer. Nowadays, objects worth astronomical sums of money change hands every day in auctions, not only household objects, art and antiquities, but also securities, minerals and energy. Public procurements can also be conducted as auctions.
Using auction theory, researchers try to understand the outcomes of different rules for bidding and final prices, the auction format. The analysis is difficult, because bidders behave strategically, based on the available information. They take into consideration both what they know themselves and what they believe other bidders to know.
Robert Wilson developed the theory for auctions of objects with a common value – a value which is uncertain beforehand but, in the end, is the same for everyone. Examples include the future value of radio frequencies or the volume of minerals in a particular area. Wilson showed why rational bidders tend to place bids below their own best estimate of the common value: they are worried about the winner’s curse – that is, about paying too much and losing out.
Paul Milgrom formulated a more general theory of auctions that not only allows common values, but also private values that vary from bidder to bidder. He analysed the bidding strategies in a number of well-known auction formats, demonstrating that a format will give the seller higher expected revenue when bidders learn more about each other’s estimated values during bidding.
Over time, societies have allocated ever more complex objects among users, such as landing slots and radio frequencies. In response, Milgrom and Wilson invented new formats for auctioning off many interrelated objects simultaneously, on behalf of a seller motivated by broad societal benefit rather than maximal revenue. In 1994, the US authorities first used one of their auction formats to sell radio frequencies to telecom operators. Since then, many other countries have followed suit.
“This year’s Laureates in Economic Sciences started out with fundamental theory and later used their results in practical applications, which have spread globally. Their discoveries are of great benefit to society,” says Peter Fredriksson, chair of the Prize Committee.



2020年9月19日 星期六

MODELS OF MY LIFE: 小羅斯幅總統的"威脅" 最高法院擴編技倆

昨天1500沒收到 不過我當時已寄出 你今明可收到 **** 你好~我想請問你們有賣這三本書嗎?
我需要原文書喔~
1.Models of My Life(作者:Herbert Simon) Return to product information

Models of My Life (Paperback)

by Herbert A. Simon (Author) 只有前一本 MODELS OF MY LIFE 建議你去AMAZON等處買 她們三四千元 (我算2000元好啦 因為是10年的書)

***2020.9.20

 

Erwin Chemerinsky, Berkeley Law dean, wrote this op-ed for the
Los Angeles Times
.

Op-Ed: Democrats have a secret weapon to thwart a rapid Ginsburg replacement. They should use it

Senate Majority Leader Mitch McConnell has vowed to rapidly move on any Trump nomination
Senate Majority Leader Mitch McConnell has vowed to rapidly move on any Trump nomination to replace Supreme Court Justice Ruth Bader Ginsburg.
(J. Scott Applewhite / Associated Press)

Wouldn’t it be nice if Democrats and Republicans could just agree that the fair and right course would be to not replace Justice Ruth Bader Ginsburg until after the presidential inauguration in January? We could simply stick, for now, with the precedent established by Senate Majority Leader Mitch McConnell when he refused to hold a vote on the nomination of Merrick Garland to replace Justice Antonin Scalia.

At the time, nearly nine months before the 2016 presidential election, he declared, “The American people should have a voice in the selection of their next Supreme Court justice. Therefore, this vacancy should not be filled until we have a new president.”

But just hours after the announcement of Ginsburg’s death on Friday, McConnell declared, “President Trump’s nominee will receive a vote on the floor of the United States Senate.”

There is little Democrats can do to stop Trump from nominating someone and the Republicans from confirming that person quickly, if that’s what they choose to do. Republicans hold a 53-47 majority in the Senate, and they have eliminated the use of the filibuster in Supreme Court nominations. So the hope must be that four Republican senators — perhaps those facing tight reelection races — will have the courage to stand up to their party and refuse to allow a confirmation to be rushed through.

That is probably a distant hope. So far, Senate Republicans have shown little inclination to stand up to Trump and McConnell, as was evident in their confirming Brett Kavanaugh for the Supreme Court, despite compelling testimony about an alleged sexual assault and perjury — and despite clear evidence that he lacked judicial temperament. Nor did Republicans demonstrate any independence or courage during the impeachment of Trump.

That leaves Democrats with few cards to play at a crucial moment for our democracy. The stakes are enormous. Last term, with Ginsburg on the bench, the court handed down surprising 5-4 decisions to protect individual rights, including a decision to strike down Louisiana’s restrictive abortion law and to invalidate Trump’s rescission of the Deferred Action for Childhood Arrivals program. If Ginsburg is replaced by a hard-line conservative who puts politics and feelings ahead of the law, the chance of such rulings will evaporate.

On the current court, Chief Justice John G. Roberts Jr. is ideologically in the middle. To be sure, he is to the right of America’s current political center, but at times he joins with the liberals, including in a vote to uphold the Affordable Care Act. If Ginsburg is replaced with someone from the far right, like Judge Amy Coney Barrett, who is frequently mentioned as a likely nominee, there will be five justices substantially more conservative than Roberts. There would be virtually no hope that abortion rights could survive such a court, and little chance of checking Trump.

One way for Democrats to make clear they will not tolerate Republicans trying to fill this seat in advance of the election would be for them to pledge that, if they take the White House and Senate in November, they will increase the size of the Supreme Court to 13 justices.

The number of justices on the court is set by federal law, not the Constitution. Since its beginnings, it has ranged from having between five and 10 members. Since the 1860s, it has remained at nine.

When President Franklin Roosevelt suggested expanding the Supreme Court in the 1930s to overcome court hostility to the New Deal, he was repudiated for trying to pack the court. But the current situation is different. This would be a response to chicanery by Republicans.

What happened with Garland’s nomination was unprecedented, and Democrats rightly believe it was a stolen seat. After Scalia’s death in February 2016, President Obama moved quickly, nominating Garland the next month.

Prior to that time, there had been 24 Supreme Court vacancies in presidential election years. In 21 instances, the Senate confirmed the nominee and in three instances it did not. But never before had the Senate refused to hold hearings and vote. If Republicans now rapidly confirm a replacement for Ginsburg, an antidote from the Democrats will be necessary.

The threat of increasing the size of the court to 13 might be enough to discourage Republicans from their dirty tricks. But if they do it anyway, and the November election produces a Democratic win in the White House and a Democratic majority in the Senate, Congress would be totally justified in increasing the size of the court.

It shouldn’t have to come to this. Republicans should be trying to bridge differences rather than inflaming the situation. It is sad that just hours after Ginsburg’s death the focus is on the political machinations rather than her legacy.

No other justice in history has become a popular icon in the way she did. She modeled for all of us in how to spend a life working to make society and individual lives better. We only can hope for a new justice in her mold.

Erwin Chemerinsky is dean of the UC Berkeley School of Law and a contributing writer to Opinion.

2020年8月31日 星期一

"You will receive the prize within ten years." By Walter Goldberg,CMU 與瑞典的 Gothenburg 大學會議 (1969)




1969年上半年,CMU 與瑞典的 Gothenburg 大學在瑞典的Aspenäs 合開類似"電腦競賽與企業管理"會議*。
聊天時,談到剛創始的諾貝爾經濟學獎 (許多人認為,經濟學家與物理學等科學獎德主同台受獎,褻瀆諾貝爾獎......)。
瑞典的主要與會者,商業經濟學家 (business economist) Walter Goldberg** 轉向H. A. Simon 說,"You will receive the prize within ten years."
Simon 自認為機會小,因為他50年代的主要學說有限理性 (Bounded Rationality) ,在美國似乎沒人提了..... (參考 Models of My Life By Herbert Simon, Basic Books, 1991, 頁320 (該章標題:From Nobel to Now . 我2020年8月31日才發現該頁錯把 Gothenburg寫成 Gothenberg。)



*這次2周的會議,CMU 的幾位名師都參加,參考 Organizing Industrial Development
Rolf H. Wolff 編集Organizing Industrial Development - 378 ページ - Google ブック検索結果

**主要著作
Efficiency of Organizations

1965 - 448 pages

編集Aggregate Planning and Control: A Constrained Non-linear Programming Approach, 第 1~4 号
A Study of Group Decision Making in a Management Game  1970
 

Herbert Simon. The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1978


Herbert Simon

Facts

Herbert A. Simon
Photo from the Nobel Foundation archive.
Herbert A. Simon
The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1978
Born: 15 June 1916, Milwaukee, WI, USA
Died: 9 February 2001, Pittsburgh, PA, USA
Affiliation at the time of the award: Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, PA, USA
Prize motivation: "for his pioneering research into the decision-making process within economic organizations."
Contribution: Work in a number of fields, including the methodology of science, applied mathematical statistics, operations analysis, economics, and business administration His work is synthesized in a new theory of organizational decision-making.
Prize share: 1/1

Life

Herbert Simon was born in Milwaukee, Wisconsin in the United States. His mother was a pianist and his father an electrical engineer who had migrated from Germany. His maternal uncle, an economist, sparked his interest in the social sciences. He first studied at the University of Chicago and was awarded a PhD in political science in 1943. After working at the University of California, Berkeley, and then at Illinois Institute of Technology in Chicago, he moved to Carnegie Mellon University in 1949. Herbert Simon was married with three children.

Work

Herbert Simon combined different scientific disciplines and considered new factors in economic theories. Established economic theories held that enterprises and entrepreneurs all acted in completely rational ways, with the maximization of their own profit as their only goal. In contrast, Simon held that when making choices all people deviate from the strictly rational, and described companies as adaptable systems, with physical, personal, and social components. Through these perspectives, he was able to write about decision-making processes in modern society in an entirely new way.
To cite this section
MLA style: Herbert A. Simon – Facts. NobelPrize.org. Nobel Media AB 2020. Mon. 31 Aug 2020.

Herbert Simon

Biographical

Iwas born in Milwaukee, Wisconsin, on June 15, 1916. My father, an electrical engineer, had come to the United States in 1903 after earning his engineering diploma at the Technische Hochschule of Darmstadt, Germany. He was an inventor and designer of electrical control gear, later also a patent attorney. An active leader in professional and civic affairs, he received an honorary doctorate from Marquette University for his many activities in the community. My mother, an accomplished pianist, was a third generation American, her forebears having been ’48ers who immigrated from Prague and Köln. Among my European ancestors were piano builders, goldsmiths, and vintners but to the best of my knowledge, no professionals of any kind. The Merkels in Köln were Lutherans, the Goldschmidts in Prague and the Simons in Ebersheim, Jews.
My home nurtured in me an early attachment to books and other things of the intellect, to music, and to the out of doors. I received an excellent general education from the public elementary and high schools in Milwaukee, supplemented by the fine science department of the public library and the many books I found at home. School work was interesting but not difficult, leaving me plenty of time for sandlot baseball and football, for hiking and camping, for reading and for many extracurricular activities during my high school years. A brother, five years my senior, while not a close companion, gave me some anticipatory glimpses of each stage of growing up. Our dinner table at home was a place for discussion and debate – often political, sometimes scientific.
Until well along in my high school years, my interests were quite dispersed, although they were increasingly directed toward science – of what sort I wasn’t sure. For most adolescents, science means physics, mathematics, chemistry, or biology – those are the subjects to which they are exposed in school. The idea that human behavior may be studied scientifically is never hinted until much later in the educational process – it was certainly not conveyed by history or “civics” courses as they were then taught.
My case was different. My mother’s younger brother, Harold Merkel, had studied economics at the University of Wisconsin under John R. Commons. Uncle Harold had died after a brief career with the National Industrial Conference Board, but his memory was always present in our household as an admired model, as were some of his books on economics and psychology. In that way I discovered the social sciences. Uncle Harold having been an ardent formal debater, I followed him in that activity too.
In order to defend free trade, disarmament, the single tax and other unpopular causes in high school debates, I was led to a serious study of Ely’s economics textbook, Norman Angell’s The Great Illusion, Henry George’s Progress and Poverty, and much else of the same sort.
By the time I was ready to enter the University of Chicago, in 1933, I had a general sense of direction. The social sciences, I thought, needed the same kind of rigor and the same mathematical underpinnings that had made the “hard” sciences so brilliantly successful. I would prepare myself to become a mathematical social scientist. By a combination of formal training and self study, the latter continuing systematically well into the 1940s, I was able to gain a broad base of knowledge in economics and political science, together with reasonable skills in advanced mathematics, symbolic logic, and mathematical statistics. My most important mentor at Chicago was the econometrician and mathematical economist, Henry Schultz, but I studied too with Rudolf Carnap in logic, Nicholas Rashevsky in mathematical biophysics, and Harold Lasswell and Charles Merriam in political science. I also made a serious study of graduate-level physics in order to strengthen and practice my mathematical skills and to gain an intimate knowledge of what a “hard” science was like, particularly on the theoretical side. An unexpected by-product of the latter study has been a lifelong interest in the philosophy of physics and several publications on the axiomatization of classical mechanics.
My career was settled at least as much by drift as by choice. An undergraduate field study for a term paper developed an interest in decision-making in organizations. On graduation in 1936, the term paper led to a research assistantship with Clarence E. Ridley in the field of municipal administration, carrying out investigations that would now be classified as operations research. The research assistantship led to the directorship, from 1939 to 1942, of a research group at the University of California, Berkeley, engaged in the same kinds of studies. By arrangement with the University of Chicago, I took my doctoral exams by mail and moonlighted a dissertation on administrative decision-making during my three years at Berkeley.
When our research grant was exhausted, in 1942, jobs were not plentiful and my military obligations were uncertain. I secured a position in political science at Illinois Institute of Technology by the intercession of a friend who was leaving. The return to Chicago had important, but again largely unanticipated, consequences for me. At that time, the Cowles Commission for Research in Economics was located at the University of Chicago. Its staff included Jacob Marschak and Tjalling Koopmans who were then directing the graduate work of such students as Kenneth Arrow, Leo Hurwicz, Lawrence Klein, and Don Patinkin. Oscar Lange, not yet returned to Poland, Milton Friedman, and Franco Modigliani frequently participated in the Cowles staff seminars, and I also became a regular participant.
That started me on a second education in economics, supplementing the Walrasian theory and Neyman-Pearson statistics I had learned earlier from Henry Schultz (and from Jerzy Neyman in Berkeley) with a careful study of Keyne’s General Theory (made comprehensible by the mathematical models proposed by MeadeHicks, and Modigliani), and the novel econometric techniques being introduced by Frisch and investigated by the Cowles staff. With considerable excitement, too, we examined Samuelson‘s new papers on comparative statics and dynamics.
I was soon co-opted by Marschak into participating in the study he and Sam Schurr were directing of the prospective economic effects of atomic energy. Taking responsibility for the macroeconomic parts of that study, I used as my analytic tools both classical Cobb-Douglas functions, and the new activity analysis being developed by Koopmans. Although I had earlier published papers on tax incidence (1943) and technological development (1947), the atomic energy project was my real baptism in economic analysis. My interest in mathematical economics having been aroused, I continued active work on problems in that domain, mainly in the period from 1950 to 1955. It was during this time that I worked out the relations between causal ordering and identifiability – coming for the first time in contact with the related work of Herman Wold – discovered and proved (with David Hawkins) the Hawkins-Simon theorem on the conditions for the existence of positive solution vectors for input-output matrices, and developed (with Albert Ando) theorems on near-decomposability and aggregation.
In 1949, Carnegie Institute of Technology received an endowment to establish a Graduate School of Industrial Administration. I left Chicago for Pittsburgh to participate with G.L. Bach, William W. Cooper, and others in developing the new school. Our goal was to place business education on a foundation of fundamental studies in economics and behavioral science. We were fortunate to pick a time for launching this venture when the new management science techniques were just appearing on the horizon, together with the electronic computer. As one part of the effort, I engaged with Charles Holt, and later with Franco Modigliani and John Muth, in developing dynamic programming techniques – the so-called “linear decision rules” – for aggregate inventory control and production smoothing. Holt and I derived the rules for optimal decision under certainty, then proved a certainty-equivalence theorem that permitted our technique to be applied under conditions of uncertainty. Modigliani and Muth went on to construct efficient computational algorithms. At this same time, Tinbergen and Theil were independently developing very similar techniques for national planning in the Netherlands.
Meanwhile, however, the descriptive study of organizational decision-making continued as my main occupation, in this case in collaboration with Harold Guetzkow, James March, Richard Cyert and others. Our work led us to feel increasingly the need for a more adequate theory of human problem-solving if we were to understand decisions. Allen Newell, whom I had met at the Rand Corporation in 1952, held similar views. About 1954, he and I conceived the idea that the right way to study problem-solving was to simulate it with computer programs. Gradually, computer simulation of human cognition became my central research interest, an interest that has continued to be absorbing up to the present time.
My research on problem-solving left me relatively little opportunity to do work of a more classical sort in economics. I did, however, continue to develop stochastic models to explain the observed highly-skewed distributions of sizes of business firms. That work, in collaboration with Yuji Ijiri and others, was summarized in a book published just two years ago.
In this sketch, I have said less about my work on decision-making than about my other research in economics because the former is discussed at greater length in my Nobel lecture. I have also left out of this account those very important parts of my life that have been occupied with my family and with non-scientific pursuits. One of my few important decisions, and the best, was to persuade Dorothea Pye to marry me on Christmas Day, 1937. We have been blessed in being able to share a wide range of our experiences, even to publishing together in two widely separate fields: public administration and cognitive psychology. We have shared also the pleasures and responsibilities of raising three children, none of whom seem imitative of their parents’ professional directions, but all of whom have shaped for themselves interesting and challenging lives.
My interests in organizations and administration have extended to participation as well as observation. In addition to three stints as a university department chairman, I have had several modest public assignments. One involved playing a role, in 1948, in the creation of the Economic Cooperation Administration, the agency that administered Marshall Plan aid for the U.S. Government. Another, more frustrating, was service on the President’s Science Advisory Committee during the last year of the Johnson administration and the first three years of the Nixon administration. While serving on PSAC, and during another committee assignment with the National Academy of Sciences, I have had opportunities to take part in studies of environmental protection policies. In all of this work, I have tried – I know not with what success – to apply my scientific knowledge of organizations and decision-making, and, conversely, to use these practical experiences to gain new research ideas and insights.
In the “politics” of science, which these and other activities have entailed, I have had two guiding principles – to work for the “hardening” of the social sciences so that they will be better equipped with the tools they need for their difficult research tasks; and to work for close relations between natural scientists and social scientists so that they can jointly contribute their special knowledge and skills to those many complex questions of public policy that call for both kinds of wisdom.
From Nobel Lectures, Economics 1969-1980, Editor Assar Lindbeck, World Scientific Publishing Co., Singapore, 1992
This autobiography/biography was written at the time of the award and first published in the book series Les Prix Nobel. It was later edited and republished in Nobel Lectures. To cite this document, always state the source as shown above.
Herbert A. Simon died on February 9, 2001.
Copyright © The Nobel Foundation 1978
To cite this section
MLA style: Herbert A. Simon – Biographical. NobelPrize.org. Nobel Media AB 2020. Mon. 31 Aug 2020.



Herbert Simon

Prize Lecture

Lecture to the memory of Alfred Nobel, December 8, 1978

Rational Decision-Making in Business Organizations

Read the Lecture
Pdf 657 kB
Copyright © The Nobel Foundation 1978
From Nobel Lectures, Economics 1969-1980, Editor Assar Lindbeck, World Scientific Publishing Co., Singapore, 1992
To cite this section
MLA style: Herbert A. Simon – Prize Lecture. NobelPrize.org. Nobel Media AB 2020. Mon. 31 Aug 2020.